INDEX - ECONOMIC
www.islandbreath.org  0605-04

SUBJECT: ECONOMICS OF FANTASY

SOURCE: JUAN WILSON juanwilson@mac.com

POSTED: 19 APRIL 2006 - 11:00pm HST

The Street is betting against homeowners

Wall Street bets housing bubble bursts
by Andrew Leonard on 19 April 2006 in Salon.com
How the World Works adores economic research papers with exciting titles like "Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier?" When such papers are written by the director of research of the International Monetary Fund, Raghuram G. Rajan, and not some one-man Web crank with a cartload of axes to grind, all the better. After pondering the astonishing growth, last week, of credit derivatives -- financial instruments designed to slice and dice risk and spread responsibility for it widely throughout the financial community -- we were more than ready for a 43-page analysis of whether innovations in risk management may have increased the chances of financial instability.

Rajan believes, in sum, that new developments in technology and finance have made the world better off, but "they may also create a greater (albeit still small) probability of a catastrophic meltdown." But he's not too worried, proposes a package of minor, "market friendly" reforms and generally seems to think things are on the right track. Still, he concurs with the observation expressed here last week: The new world of credit derivatives hasn't been tested by a major downturn, so we just don't know what's going to happen.

But could we be about to find out? One example Rajan used to illustrate potential problems was the housing sector. The great thing about credit derivatives, as far as a bank is concerned, is that they allow the banks to buy protection for the possibility that borrowers will default on loans. Protection in hand, the banks can then go out and make more loans, ever riskier in nature. This is precisely what has happened in the housing sector, in which banks have bent over backward to offer interest-only, no-money-down loans to customers whose credit rating is, shall we say, dicey.

Well guess what -- since last September the market for a particular kind of credit derivative, technically described as "credit default swaps on subprime ARM pools," has taken off. ("ARM" stands for "adjustable-rate mortgage," and "subprime" means the borrower has a low credit rating.) According to Mark Whitehouse of the Wall Street Journal, who does the best reporting on credit derivatives of anyone in the financial press, such derivatives doubled in price between mid-September and December of 2005. I haven't been able to find more recent data, but given the steady drumbeat of negative news from the housing sector, it's hard to imagine that the trend line has changed.

So who is doing the buying? According to Whitehouse, the main players are hedge funds that specialize in debt trading: "The new credit-default swap 'allows us to express a bearish opinion' on the housing market, says Steve Persky, managing partner at Dalton Investments, a Los Angeles hedge fund with about $1 billion in assets. 'A lot of people debate whether the housing market is overpriced, but, for sure, the credit quality of home borrowers has deteriorated.'"

The hedge funds are basically betting on the likelihood that there will be a housing sector collapse. They are short-selling the real estate business. The potential for profit is significant. "In mid-September, an investor seeking insurance on $10 million in mortgage securities with the lowest investment-grade rating of triple-B-minus, for example, could have bought a credit-default swap by agreeing to pay an annual premium of about $170,000 a year. Now, with hedge funds and others piling in to buy insurance as the housing market shows weakness, the premium on the same swap has risen to about $320,000, allowing the investor to sell the insurance at the new, higher price and pocket the difference."

So here's the deal: The smartest players on Wall Street see the housing market about to implode. So they're loading up on cutting-edge financial instruments that will theoretically protect the buyer from exposure to millions of homeowners suddenly beginning to default on their loans. And for the moment, they're making money hand over fist as the value of those derivatives rises with every new data point about slumping housing sales, slow housing starts and rising interest rates.

But what happens if the defaults do start rolling in, and the sellers of those derivatives have to make good on their obligations with cold, hard cash? Will there be enough liquidity in the system to handle the shock? Will state-of-the-art capitalism work as advertised? As Whitehouse reports, the market for credit-default swaps that could be applied to pools of home mortgage loans is new -- it's only been around since last June. Again, no one knows how it will play out.

But any prospective homeowner thinking right now about jumping into the market with a no-money-down, adjustable-rate mortgage might want to think twice. Wall Street is betting against you.

SUBJECT: ECONOMICS OF FANTASY

SOURCE: KEN TAYLOR taylork021@hawaii.rr.com

POSTED: 27 MARCH 2006 - 7:00pm HST

Well being is not measured by Gross Domestic Product

The Real Economy
by Dr. Robert Costanza Gund Institute of Ecological Economics

Stories about the economy typically focus on Gross Domestic Product (GDP), jobs, stock prices, interest rates, retail sales, consumer confidence, housing starts, taxes, and assorted other indicators. We hear things like "GDP grew at a 3% rate in the fourth quarter, indicating a recovering, healthy economy, but with room for further improvement." Or, "The Fed raised short-term interest rates again to head off inflation."

But do these reports, and the indicators they cite, really tell us how the economy is doing? What is the economy anyway? And what is this economy for?
Conventional reports on these questions are rather narrow. The "economy" we usually hear about refers only to the market economy – the value of those goods and services that are exchanged for money. Its purpose is usually taken to be to maximize the value of these goods and services– with the assumption that the more activity, the better off we are. Thus, the more GDP (which measures aggregate activity in the market economy), the better. Likewise the more contributors to GDP (such as retail sales and salaries paid to employees), the better. Predictors of more GDP in the future (such as housing starts and consumer confidence) are also important pieces of information from this perspective. Declining or even stable GDP is seen as a disaster. Growth in GDP is assumed to be government’s primary policy goal and also something that is sustainable indefinitely.

But is this what the economy is all about? Or more accurately, is this all that the economy is about? Or, is this what the economy should be about? The answer to all of these is an emphatic no. Here’s why.

Let’s start with purpose. The purpose of the economy should be to provide for the sustainable well-being of people. That goal encompasses material well-being, certainly -- but also anything else that affects well being and its sustainability. This seems obvious and non-controversial. The problem comes in determining what things actually affect well-being and in what ways.

There is substantial new research on this "science of happiness" that shows the limits of conventional economic income and consumption in contributing to well-being. Psychologist Tim Kasser in his 2003 book "The High Price of Materalism" points out, for instance, that people who focus on material consumption as a path to happiness are actually less happy and even suffer higher rates of both physical and mental illnesses than those who do not. Material consumption beyond real need is a form of psychological "junk food" that only satisfies for the moment and ultimately leads to depression, Kasser says.

Economist Richard Easterlin, a noted researcher on the determinants of happiness, has shown that well-being tends to correlate well with health, level of education, and marital status, and not very well with income. He concludes in a recent paper in the Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences that, "People make decisions assuming that more income, comfort, and positional goods will make them happier, failing to recognize that hedonic adaptation and social comparison will come into play, raise their aspirations to about the same extent as their actual gains, and leave them feeling no happier than before. As a result, most individuals spend a disproportionate amount of their lives working to make money, and sacrifice family life and health, domains in which aspirations remain fairly constant as actual circumstances change, and where the attainment of one’s goals has a more lasting impact on happiness. Hence, a reallocation of time in favor of family life and health would, on average, increase individual happiness." British economist Richard Layard’s 2005 book: "Happiness: lessons from a new science," echos many of these ideas and concludes that current economic policies are not improving happiness and that "happiness should become the goal of policy, and the progress of national happiness should be measured and analysed as closely as the growth of GNP."

Economist Robert Frank, in his 2000 book "Luxury Fever," also concludes that the nation would be better off – overall national well-being would be higher, that is – if we actually consumed less and spent more time with family and friends, working for our communities, maintaining our physical and mental health, and enjoying nature.

On this last point, there is substantial and growing evidence that natural systems contribute heavily to human well-being. In a paper published in 1997 in the journal Nature, my co-authors and I estimated the annual, non-market value of the earth’s ecosystem services is $33 trillion globally, substantially larger than global GDP. The just released UN Millennium Ecosystem Assessment is a global update and compendium of ecosystem services and their contributions to human well-being.
So, if we want to assess the "real" economy – all the things which contribute to real, sustainable, human welfare – as opposed to only the "market" economy, we have to measure the non-marketed contributions to human well-being from nature, from family, friends and other social relationships at many scales, and from health and education. One convenient way to summarize these contributions is to group them into four basic types of capital that are necessary to support the real, human-welfare-producing economy: built capital, human capital, social capital, and natural capital.

The market economy covers mainly built capital (factories, offices, and other built infrastructure and their products) and part of human capital (spending on labor), with some limited spillover into the other two. Human capital includes the health, knowledge, and all the other attributes of individual humans that allow them to function in a complex society. Social capital includes all the formal and informal networks among people: family, friends, and neighbors, as well as social institutions at all levels, like churches, social clubs, local, state, and national governments, NGO’s, and international organizations. Natural capital includes the world’s ecosystems and all the services they provide. Ecosystem services occur at many scales, from climate regulation at the global scale, to flood protection, soil formation, nutrient cycling, recreation, and aesthetic services at the local and regional scales.

So, how has the real economy been doing recently, compared to the market economy? The short answer is, not so good. How do we know? One way is through surveys of people’s life satisfaction, which have been decreasing slightly since about 1975. A second approach is an aggregate measure of the real economy that has been developed as an alternative to GDP called the Genuine Progress Indicator, or GPI.

Let’s first take a quick look at the problems with GDP as a measure of true human well-being. GDP is not only limited – measuring only marketed economic activity or gross income -- it also counts all of this activity as positive. It does not separate desirable, well-being-enhancing activity from undesirable well-being-reducing activity. For example, an oil spill increases GDP because someone has to clean it up, but it obviously detracts from society’s well-being. From the perspective of GDP, more crime, more sickness, more war, more pollution, more fires, storms, and pestilence are all potentially good things, because they can increase marketed activity in the economy.

GDP also leaves out many things that do enhance well-being but are outside the market. For example, the unpaid work of parents caring for their own children at home doesn't show up, but if these same parents decide to work outside the home to pay for child care, GDP suddenly increases. The non-marketed work of natural capital in providing clean air and water, food, natural resources, and other ecosystem services doesn’t adequately show up in GDP, either, but if those services are damaged and we have to pay to fix or replace them, then GDP suddenly increases. Finally, GDP takes no account of the distribution of income among individuals. But it is well-known that an additional $1 worth of income produces more well-being if one is poor rather than rich. It is also clear that a highly skewed income distribution has negative effects on a society’s social capital.

The GPI addresses these problems by separating the positive from the negative components of marketed economic activity, adding in estimates of the value of non-marketed goods and services provided by natural, human, and social capital, and adjusting for income-distribution effects. While it is by no means a perfect representation of the real well-being of the nation, GPI is a much better approximation than GDP. As Amarta Sen and others have noted, it is much better to be approximately right in these measures than precisely wrong.

Comparing GDP and GPI for the US shows that, while GDP has steadily increased since 1950, with the occasional dip or recession, GPI peaked in about 1975 and has been gradually decreasing ever since. From the perspective of the real economy, as opposed to just the market economy, the U.S. has been in recession since 1975. As already mentioned, this picture is also consistent with survey-based research on people's stated life-satisfaction. We are now in a period of what Herman Daly has called "un-economic growth," where further growth in marketed economic activity (GDP) is actually reducing well-being on balance rather than enhancing it. In terms of the four capitals, while built capital has grown, human, social and natural capital have declined or remained constant and more than canceled out the gains in built capital.

In the last four years, the decline in domestic GPI has picked up speed. While U.S. GPI was beginning to trend upward again at the end of the Clinton years, the policies of the Bush administration have lead to a significant worsening of income distribution (thereby further decreasing social capital), an increasing depletion of natural capital, and worsening human capital through decreased spending on education and health and loss of jobs. And the Bush team has certainly not compensated for these negatives with a stellar performance in the built capital component (GDP). While the dollar incomes of some wealthy individuals may have improved over this period, the overall well-being of the nation has significantly declined. Further, the psychological evidence is that even the well-being (as opposed to income) of the wealthy individuals has probably not improved very much and may even have declined. From the perspective of the real economy, the country is in rapidly worsening shape.

Is the news all bad? No. We recently estimated the GPI of the State of Vermont and of Burlington, the state’s largest city, and found that Vermont’s and Burlington’s GPI per capita had increased over the entire 1950-2000 period and is now more than double the national average. This was due to Vermont’s attention to protecting and enhancing natural, human, and social capital in balance with gains in built capital -- accomplished through the application of strong, local democratic principles and processes still actively at work in Vermont.

The lesson from Vermont, and from similar analyses done at the regional level in other locales, is that there is significant variation across the country in trends in well-being and quality of life, and plenty of good examples we can learn from to improve the overall well-being of the country.

How can we apply these lessons to get out of the real recession in human well-being at the national scale that we have been in since 1975? Several policies have been suggested that would help to turn things around

• Shifting our primary national policy goal from increasing marketed economic activity (GDP) to maximizing national well-being (GPI or something similar). This would allow us to see the interconnections between built, human, social, and natural capital and build well-being in a balanced and sustainable way.

• Reforming the tax system to send the right incentives by taxing negatives (pollution, depletion of natural capital, overconsumption) rather than positives (labor, savings, investment). Recent tax reforms have decreased well-being by promoting a greater income gap, natural resource depletion, and increased pollution.

• Reforming international trade to promote well-being over mere GDP growth. This implies protecting natural capital, labor rights, and democratic self-determination first and then allowing trade, rather than promoting the current trade rules that ride roughshod over all other societal values and ignore all non-market contributions to well-being.

• Implementing local complementary currency systems to encourage more local economic activity and help build social capital. There are more than 4000 local currency systems in operation today, including "Ithaca hours" in Ithaca, NY and "Burlington Bread" in Burlington, VT. While these systems have so far not played a major role in local economies, the potential for their expanded use is huge.

• Further reforming campaign finance laws so that the needs and welfare of individuals are more fully and accurately expressed in the national democratic process, rather than the needs and welfare of those who currently fund political campaigns. As Tom Prugh, myself, and Herman Daly have argued in our book "The Local Politics of Global Sustainability," implementing strong democracy (as opposed to the weak and ineffective sham of democracy we currently see at the national scale) is an essential prerequisite to building a sustainable and desirable future.

Ultimately, getting out of the 25-year recession in well-being we are currently in will require us to look beyond the limited definition of the "economy" we read about in the newspapers, and recognize what the real economy is and what it is for. We must not allow deceptive accounting practices – analogous to those that caused the Enron and WorldCom debacles – to paint an inaccurate and ultimately destructive picture of how "well" we are doing. Alternatives are available, but they need significant further discussion and research.

With nothing less than our current and future well-being at stake, we can certainly afford to devote greater effort to learning how to adequately understand and measure it. If we want the things that really matter to our well-being to count, we must learn how to recognize and count them, and use that information to inform policy in a real democracy.


Dr. Robert Costanza
Gund Professor of Ecological Economics and Director
Gund Institute of Ecological Economics
Rubenstein School of Environment and Natural Resources
The University of Vermont
590 Main Street. Burlington VT 05405-1708

phone: 802.656.2974
fax: 802.656.2995

email: Robert.Costanza@uvm.edu


www.islandbreath.org

Pau